Friday, September 24, 2010

Isramart llc: The time is right for a carbon tax

www.isra-mart.com

Isramart llc news:

The case for a carbon tax is a compelling one, given our current macroeconomic quandary and our apparent inability to deal with climate change. Each of these factors alone can make the case persuasively. When we take them together, the tax becomes even more convincing as a solution to some seemingly insurmountable problems.

Like it or not, for the foreseeable future tax increases are a necessity. The United States' 2009 federal deficit was $1.4 trillion — almost 10 percent of GDP. By comparison, at about 10 percent the U.S. did better than newsmakers Greece (13.6 percent) and Spain (11.2 percent) but worse than, for example, Portugal, France and Romania.

Even if we assume that the U.S. economy returns to health with robust growth, the long-term full employment structural deficit was estimated at $475 billion earlier this year. While many would like to erase the structural deficit by slashing spending, we know from past legislative behavior that once elected, lawmakers have little appetite for axing special projects in their own districts or states.

Living indefinitely with massive deficits is not an option. Even if the Chinese continue to buy our debt, it is morally indefensible to mortgage our future. Most tea party supporters don't seem to realize that without equal spending cuts, the tax cuts they crave will amount simply to more deficit spending and higher future taxes to be paid by their children and grandchildren.

But while tax increases coupled with spending cuts is good long-term macroeconomic policy, in the fragile state of the U.S. economy today these will only dampen the demand that can spur economic recovery. This is our quandary.

To minimize short-term macroeconomic impacts, we need a tax that commits to start at a low rate and then to rise over time, generating large revenues in the future. This policy would send a credible message to capital markets that the U.S. is getting its finances in order, and assure the primacy of the U.S. dollar in world capital markets.

But what kind of tax can do this? Answer: A carbon tax that begins at say $5 per ton of CO2, rising at a rate of 4 percent plus the rate of inflation. If inflation averages 3 percent per year, over 10 years tax rates double. Over 20 years, they quadruple and over 30 years, they grow eightfold. To get an idea of the revenue potential, assume such a carbon tax stabilized CO2 emissions at 2007 levels. In the first year of the tax, revenue would be $37 billion. But in the 10th, revenue would be $74 billion and after 20 years, it would be $148 billion. After 30 years, revenues could reach $296 billion. But the short-term effect on consumers would be minimal, raising gasoline and heating oil prices by 5 cents per gallon. Even a $10 per ton carbon tax would have a benign effect on the economy.

As a general rule, taxes hinder economic efficiency because they raise the cost of doing business and reduce workers' incentives to work and save. But linking a tax to a pollutant can have the beneficial effects of reducing pollution by encouraging the development of nonpolluting technologies. Unlike higher income tax rates, a carbon tax would not weaken incentives to work and save.

Rather, by making carbon-intensive products more expensive, the tax would encourage consumers to choose less polluting goods. If some want to keep buying large amounts of carbon-intensive products, those people will have to pay the rest of us for that privilege. So a carbon tax is fair in the sense that it would apply to all of us - rich, poor and middle class.

Any justification for a carbon tax must rest on the science of climate change and the economics of its impacts on GDP and quality of life. There is a huge literature on these topics. Our reading of the science of climate change is that the phenomenon is real, and will loom ever larger as China and India join the club of advanced nations. When most economists assess the costs and benefits of policies to cut carbon emissions, they conclude that draconian actions to quash carbon emissions are not called for. We do not need to scrap the existing infrastructure of energy use tied to fossil fuels. But, as we replace the infrastructure over time, we must do so with renewables and fuels that leave lighter carbon footprints.

The beauty of a carbon tax that starts low but grows over time is that it will accomplish this energy transition with minimal macroeconomic disruptions. For example, a $5 per ton carbon tax initially will raise the cost of coal by almost 50 percent. Since coal plants enjoy a big cost advantage over other fuels, for the most part coal plants will not be retired prematurely. But when they are, cost-conscious engineers will weigh the projected future costs of a new coal plant against other options.

In 30 or 40 years, we could fully replace the electricity generating infrastructure with low or zero carbon emissions, a move that makes good business sense and good environmental sense. If we start the carbon tax today, we begin to reconfigure the energy infrastructure of the U.S. economy. The reason most economists prefer a carbon tax over a cap-and-trade system is that it avoids the extreme volatility of carbon prices. In a cap-and-trade system, if regulators issue too few allowances, carbon allowance prices can skyrocket as they did in Europe. We don't need the uncertainty that cap-and-trade would create; hopefully, that policy is off the table for good. But Washington does desperately need both the tax revenues that a carbon tax can bring, and a sensible climate change policy.